Coase and the Myth of Fisher Body

12 September 2006 at 8:54 am 6 comments

| Peter Klein |

I vividly recall, at the inaugural meeting of the International Society for New Institutional Economics in 1997, a discussion about the best empirical strategy for that emerging discipline. Harold Demsetz stood up and said “Please, no more papers about Fisher Body and GM!” The Fisher-GM case had become the canonical example of holdup in transaction cost economics and was considered stale and even trite. Ronald Coase, who was at the podium, replied (I’m paraphrasing from memory) “Sorry, Harold, that is exactly the subject of my next paper!”

The GM-Fisher case was introduced into the transaction cost literature by Klein, Crawford, and Alchian in their 1978 paper “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents and the Competitive Contracting Process.” They cited the case as a classic example of vertical integration designed to mitigate holdup in the presence of asset specificity. As the story is told, Fisher refused to locate its plants near G.M. assembly plants and to change its production technology in the face of an unanticipated increase in the demand for car bodies. This led G.M. to terminate its existing ten-year supply contract with Fisher and to acquire full ownership of Fisher.

The basic facts of the account, and the interpretation of these facts, were challenged in five independently written papers, all appearing in 2000. Three of the papers, by Coase, Casadesus-Masanell and Spulber, and Freeland, are in the April 2000 Journal of Law and Economics. A fourth paper by Helper, MacDuffie, and Sabel appears in Industiral and Corporate Change and one by Miwa and Ramseyer is in the Michigan Law Review. These papers showed that nearly every detail of the canonical account is wrong.

First, as Coase reveals, the original ten-year supply contract included provisions that GM would acquire 60 percent of Fisher’s stock and that three of the five members of Fisher’s finance committee would be appointed by G.M. Moreover, in 1921 one of the Fisher brothers became a director of GM, with two other brothers joining him in 1924, one of whom became president of GM’s Cadillac division. A fourth brother was added to the board in 1926 when GM acquired the remainder of Fisher’s stock. As Coase points out, the interests of the two companies were sufficiently aligned during the period covered by the original contract that it is unlikely that Fisher would have used the contract to extract rents from GM. Also, contrary to the standard story, Fisher did in fact build eight new body plants between 1922 and 1925 that were close to GM facilities and had incentives to use the most efficient technology available. Helper, MacDuffie and Sabel suggest that vertical integration promoted collaborative learning, while Casadesus-Masanell and Spulber argue it improved the coordination of production and inventories. In short, GM did not acquire the remaining 40 percent of Fisher’s stock in response to an inappropriate alignment between transactional attributes and an existing governance structure. Rather, the long-term contract signed in 1919 was adequate for mitigating holdup in the face of asset specificity and uncertainty, and was replaced by vertical integration for secondary reasons.

Coase’s latest article — yes, at age 96 he is still publishing in top-tier journals — appears in the Summer 2006 Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. Titled “The Conduct of Economics: The Example of Fisher Body and General Motors,” the article traces the development and evolution of the canonical account, its challenge by Coase and others, and Benjamin Klein’s response to the challenge (which Coase finds shamefully inadequate). The most interesting section is the last one, in which Coase tries to explain how economists came to accept the fable. (Coase has performed this same exercise before, of course, most famously in his 1974 article on lighthouses.) For me, Occam’s Razor suggests a simple explanation: economists like illustrative examples (more so, in reality, than comprehensive econometric evidence, despite their protests to the contrary), and Klein, Crawford, and Alchian offered one that seemed intuitively plausible, was easy to remember, and was useful for pedagogical purposes. No one bothered to check the details because there seemed to be no need to do so.

Coase’s explanation is more complex. First, because he thinks the basic asset specificity-holdup-opportunism story of transaction cost economics is wrong, he thinks researchers have exaggerated the importance of this case because it supports what would otherwise be a suspect theory. I don’t agree with Coase here, because the holdup story is supported by more than mere armchair speculation, but by dozens — perhaps hundreds — of case studies, econometric investigations, and other forms of empirical analysis. (My summary of this literature is here.) The truth of the basic holdup story is not dependent on the facts of one particular — if highly celebrated — case.

Coase has a broader purpose in mind, however. He uses this episode to criticize economists for overreliance on deductive methods, for failing to investigate the “facts on the ground,” and for general sloppiness in empirical work.

If it is believed that their theory tells us how people would behave in different circumstances, it will appear unnecessary to many to make a detailed study of how they did in fact act. This leads to a very casual attitude toward checking the facts. If it is believed that certain contractual arrangements will lead to opportunistic behavior, it is not surprising that economists misinterpret the evidence and find what they expect to find.

This is not quite fair, because Coase has not subjected his own, preferred, inductive approach to equally critical scrutiny. In his own hands, Coase’s method has led to several brilliant insights. In the average economist’s hands, however, I shudder to think of the consequences. After all, it was Coase himself who said of the “old” institutional economists: “Without a theory, they had nothing to pass on except a mass of descriptive material waiting for a theory, or a fire.” Let’s not throw out sound transaction cost and incomplete-contracting theory with the GM-Fisher bathwater.

Entry filed under: - Klein -, Business/Economic History, New Institutional Economics, Recommended Reading, Strategic Management, Theory of the Firm.

Introducing Guest Blogger David Gordon Mises’s Bureaucracy

6 Comments Add your own

  • 1. Jung-Chin Shen  |  13 September 2006 at 1:46 pm

    Excellent post. Since I have the privilege to read Steven N. S. Cheung’s Chinese books, I would like to briefly mention his reflections on this issue about his working experience with Coase. Alchian is Cheung’s dissertation advisor (Demsetz has also been very influential), but he most closely exchanges ideas with Coase, partly because of his postdoc experience at the Department of Economics of the University of Chicago. Coase’s “inductive” approach perhaps can date back to his education training in UK, which is said as to why he includes the article, “The Lighthouse in Economics,” into his 1988 book. However, perhaps the best article on this issue is not the lighthouse article, but Cheung’s The Fable of the Bees, because the latter article gives an unambiguous account against the blackboard economics. It is actually Coase who suggested Cheung to conduct an investigation on the topic. In the last paragraph of the bees article, Cheung says,

    “I have no grounds for criticizing Meade and other economists who follow the Pigovian tradition for their use of the bee example to illustrate a theoretical point: certainly, resource allocation would in general differ from what is observed if the factors were “unpaid.” My main criticism, rather, concerns their approach to economic inquiry in failing to investigate the real-world situation and in arriving at policy implications out of sheer imagination. As a result, their work contributes little to our understanding of the actual economic system.”

    When the three GM-Fisher Body articles came out at the Journal of Law and Economics, I was taking a course from Robert Gibbons of MIT who was shortly visiting INSEAD at that time. He also said that the three articles do not bother him at all since he finds holdup is a very useful concept for a researcher.

    Cheung has been very important to bridge Coase and North and Barzel. In his 1990 book, North said his understanding of economic organization should be attributed to Cheung. But I find no such acknowledgement in Barzel’s property rights book, even though he says that Cheung’s papers are ground-breaking in the book. Finally, the Washington approach is getting closer to the neoclassical economics relative to Coase’s approach. Another thing that I find interesting is that Oliver Williamson rarely cites Cheung’s work (only once?), even though he heavily cites Coase, Alchian, Demsetz, North, and even Barzel.

    Although Cheung had been influential during the period of China economic reform, and he says that Milton Friedman finally agrees that he is wrong about his objection to Cheung’s decision to go back to Hong Kong, I find most of his most important works were done when he was in the US. After some infamous events a couple of years ago, I rarely heard more news about Cheung since ever.

  • 2. Lawrence H. White  |  28 September 2006 at 4:39 pm

    Here is some news about Cheung : he has been charged with faking Chinese antiques.

  • 3. Gary Shiu  |  28 September 2006 at 8:35 pm

    Actually Barzel did acknowledge Cheung’s important influence on his thouhgts:

    First he did so in his 1995 introductory essay for his collected papers and secondly when he wrote a small pamplet celebrating the publication of Steven Cheung’s collected essays (in English) late last year.

    Gary Shiu

  • 4. Gary Shiu  |  28 September 2006 at 8:48 pm

    Steven has recently published a series of books on price theory called Economic Explanation (in Chinese). In these books, he lays out clearly the Washingtonian approach to transaction costs economics.

  • 5. Danny L. McDaniel  |  10 January 2010 at 11:16 pm

    The modern model for vertical intergration is Coke-Cola and its bottlers. The bottlers no longer exist with Coke owning all the bottling and distribution. The main reason for this form of vertical intergration was the soft drink industry wet to bottling in plastic containers instead of glass. This allowed their delivery truck to carry more product since plastic is lighter than glass, and the number of law suits form breakage in grocery store went to zero after plastic replaced glass. Remember back a few decades ago when you visited a store you could always from the soft drink isle from the sound of shoes sticking to the floor.

    Vertical interfration as argued by Coase is too painfully to read because of the emotional ties to GM-Fisher Body and the decline of midwest industrial capacity. Fisher Body did keep quality in check during its existence. Fisher Body employees had more pride in their workmanship than most other GM employees.

    Danny L. McDaniel
    Lafayette, Indiana

  • 6. Decidedly Happenstance  |  8 May 2024 at 3:34 pm

    Nice post thannks for sharing

Leave a comment

Trackback this post  |  Subscribe to the comments via RSS Feed


Authors

Nicolai J. Foss | home | posts
Peter G. Klein | home | posts
Richard Langlois | home | posts
Lasse B. Lien | home | posts

Guests

Former Guests | posts

Networking

Recent Posts

Categories

Feeds

Our Recent Books

Nicolai J. Foss and Peter G. Klein, Organizing Entrepreneurial Judgment: A New Approach to the Firm (Cambridge University Press, 2012).
Peter G. Klein and Micheal E. Sykuta, eds., The Elgar Companion to Transaction Cost Economics (Edward Elgar, 2010).
Peter G. Klein, The Capitalist and the Entrepreneur: Essays on Organizations and Markets (Mises Institute, 2010).
Richard N. Langlois, The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism: Schumpeter, Chandler, and the New Economy (Routledge, 2007).
Nicolai J. Foss, Strategy, Economic Organization, and the Knowledge Economy: The Coordination of Firms and Resources (Oxford University Press, 2005).
Raghu Garud, Arun Kumaraswamy, and Richard N. Langlois, eds., Managing in the Modular Age: Architectures, Networks and Organizations (Blackwell, 2003).
Nicolai J. Foss and Peter G. Klein, eds., Entrepreneurship and the Firm: Austrian Perspectives on Economic Organization (Elgar, 2002).
Nicolai J. Foss and Volker Mahnke, eds., Competence, Governance, and Entrepreneurship: Advances in Economic Strategy Research (Oxford, 2000).
Nicolai J. Foss and Paul L. Robertson, eds., Resources, Technology, and Strategy: Explorations in the Resource-based Perspective (Routledge, 2000).