Diamond-Dybvig (1983) and the Financial Crisis

13 October 2010 at 11:06 pm 8 comments

| Peter Klein |

I started writing a really clever post about the famous Diamond paper (with Philip Dybvig) on financial intermediation and bank runs, its relevance for the financial crisis, and its elevated status in light of Monday’s Nobel announcement. Then I remembered that the author is Douglas Diamond, not Peter Diamond. Doh!

So I’ll try a different framing. “Speaking of guys named Diamond. . . .” The Diamond-Dybvig model, presented in a 1983 JPE article, has become famous enough to spawn an extensive secondary literature (and even sports its own Wikipedia entry). In a nutshell, it models fractional-reserve banks as intermediaries transforming illiquid assets into liquid liabilities and depicts the relationship among depositors as a coordination game with two Nash equilibria, one in which nobody tries to withdraw his funds because he believes no one else will try to withdraw his funds, and one in which everyone tries to withdraw their funds because they believe everyone else will try to withdraw their funds. Bank runs, in other words, constitute a Pareto-inferior Nash equilibrium. This framework led to extensive discussions about deposit insurance, option clauses, and other mechanisms to prevent the bad equilibrium by affecting depositors’ beliefs about solvency. (My former colleague Larry White devotes nearly a chapter of his Theory of Monetary Institutions to Diamond-Dybvig 1983.)

This is a hugely influential article, and I’m surprised it hasn’t been gotten more attention in the last two years. The essential fragility of a complex, interdependent, highly leveraged, fractional-reserve, implicitly government guaranteed system is at the heart of the financial crisis, so you’d think the Diamond-Dybvig framework would play an important role in the debate. But I can’t find much literature on this. The Richmond Fed devoted a special 2010 issue of its Financial Quarterly, guest edited by Ed Prescott, to the DD model, but it attracted little attention. Writes Prescott in his introduction:

Until recently, bank runs were not considered a major problem in the United States. The introduction of deposit insurance in the 1930s was considered to have essentially solved this problem. There had been very few bank runs since then. Much of the academic literature instead focused on the sizeable costs of moral hazard that can come with a deposit insurance system, as was seen in the savings and loan crisis of the 1980s (see, for example, White [1991]).

What the academic and policy worlds missed was just how much some of the newer (since the 1970s) financial arrangements were starting to resemble banks in that they performed maturity transformation and financed assets with liabilities that resembled demand deposits. Many of these arrangements ran into trouble during the financial crisis when they could not roll over their short-term debt. Whether these episodes match the DD equilibrium in which a solvent bank is run because of a panic is still a topic of debate. After all, a run on a bank is also perfectly consistent with a bank being insolvent.

What we do have now, however, are data that are much higher quality than are available on historical runs. Furthermore, as we will see, these financial arrangements differ along dimensions such as how excess short-term withdrawals are managed. My conjecture is that these sources of variation along with the data will provide an important source of information for not only evaluating the DD model, but also evaluating methods for dealing with a potential run.

I’m not sure what Peter Diamond would say about all this — financial intermediation is a search process, after all — but Doug Diamond was written some important popular and scholarly pieces on the crisis. Another paper (with Raghu Rajan) echoes the Austrian theory of the business cycle: “[W]hen household needs for funds are high, interest rates will rise sharply, debtors will have to shut down illiquid projects, and in extremis, will face more damaging [bank] runs. Authorities may want to push down interest rates to maintain economic activity in the face of such illiquidity, but intervention may not always be feasible, and when feasible, could encourage banks to increase leverage or fund even more illiquid projects up front. This could make all parties worse off.” Add Diamond and Rajan:

We are certainly not the first to place the emphasis for contraction and crises on the mismatch between the long duration before investment produces consumption goods, and the temporal pattern of consumption in an expansion. This dates back at least to Von Mises (1949) and the Austrian School. Von Mises placed the emphasis, though, on an artificially low initial rate of interest, induced by bank credit expansion, which makes the process of creating new goods excessively long compared with the tolerance of consumers to postpone consumption. While it is difficult to map his theory precisely to a rational expectations general equilibrium model, it would appear that Von Mises (1949) places the blame for crises squarely on the heads of overly optimistic, excessively aggressive, bankers (and on central bankers who encourage aggressive credit expansion). . . .

Summarizing our analysis, a central bank that promises to cut interest rates conditional on stress, or that is biased towards low interest rates favoring entrepreneurs, will induce banks to promise higher payouts or take more illiquid projects. This in turn can make the illiquidity crisis more severe and require a greater degree of intervention, a view reminiscent of the Austrian theory of cycles. . . .

Our model suggests that the crisis of 2007-2009 may not be unrelated to the actions of the Federal Reserve earlier in the decade, not only in convincing the market that interest rates would remain low for a sustained period following the dot-com bust because of its fears of deflation, but also in promising to intervene to pick up the pieces in case of an asset price collapse — the so-called Greenspan put.

Entry filed under: - Klein -, Austrian Economics, Bailout / Financial Crisis, People.

Two New Books on Economic Growth American Exceptionalism

8 Comments Add your own

  • 1. Arash  |  14 October 2010 at 9:47 am

    Mr. Klein,

    you may be interested in Sargent’s take on DD in relation to the financial crisis. Here the link (check p.30): http://www.minneapolisfed.org/pubs/region/10-09/sargent.pdf

    “I like to think about two polar
    models of bank crises and what government
    lender-of-last-resort and deposit
    insurance do to arrest them or promote
    them. Both models had origins in
    papers written at the Federal Reserve
    Bank of Minneapolis, one authored by
    John Kareken and Neil Wallace in 1978
    and the other by John Bryant in 1980,
    then extended by Diamond and Dybvig
    in 1983.9 I call them polar models
    because … .”

  • 2. Peter Klein  |  14 October 2010 at 10:35 am

    Thanks!

  • 3. David Hoopes  |  14 October 2010 at 2:02 pm

    Great link! Thanks Arash.

  • 4. Pietro M.  |  14 October 2010 at 4:09 pm

    When there will be a Nobel for Romer, you’ll have to write three blog posts…

  • 5. Peter Klein  |  14 October 2010 at 4:19 pm

    Good one, Pietro!

  • 6. paul e.  |  17 October 2010 at 5:08 pm

    Kevin Dowd wrote a survey paper on “Models of Banking
    Instability” in Journal of Economic Surveys vol.6 no.2

    If I recall, Selgin and White were not very impressed with
    the Diamond-Dybvig model in their Theory of Monetary
    Institutions.

    Kevin Dowd is one of the world’s leading researchers on free banking and he also has a new book out about the financial crisis.

  • 7. George Selgin  |  20 October 2010 at 7:28 am

    I’m afraid I can’t take credit for the discussion of DD in the _Theory of Monetary Institutions_, of which Larry White is sole author. I have, however, written an article about it in the Journal of Financial Services Research, called In Defense of Bank Suspension. The basic argument there is that in DD bank suspensions are costly because, basically, banks double as stores–all the goods are kept in their vaults!–so suspension=no consumption. That is (I trust readers would agree) somewhat unrewalistic! In real-world suspensions (though not in silly bank “holidays” like those of the 1930s), banks stayed open to make loans, accept deposits, and (most importantly) issue notes and arrange settlement with other banks, so that people could still shop with their banknotes and checks.

    Once you allow for this, the DD claim that you must have a central bank or deposit insurance to deal with panic-based runs–a “bad equilibrium”–without exposing people to high welfare losses, collapses. All this is setting aside (1) the question-begging implicit perfect info. assumption thyat’s requirted to allow government intervention to address panics costlessly; (2) the fact that panic based runs have in fact been very rare historically; and (3) the fact that systemic runs have been even rarer. DD gloss over the last point by simply assuming that there’s only one bank. In reality, if there are dozens or hundreds, unless every bank suffers a “bad” equilibrium at the same time, you end up not with a genuine crisis but with what Anna Schwartz calles a “psuedo” crisis, which would just mean that some banks go out of business while others prosper that much more.

    Besides all this there are many other problems with the DD model, which Dowd reviews very thoroughly.

    So why has everyone treated this utterly unrealistic model as if it were a reliable guide to policy? Why, because it’s mathematically neat, of course; and because no one has a neater one to offer. As Sargent likes to repeat, “It takes a model to beat a model.” To which my response is: “It takes real knowledge of economic history and institutions to beat unjustified assumptions about economic history and institutions.” Alas, no one listens to me!

  • 8. Jim Rose  |  28 August 2014 at 7:49 am

    Reblogged this on Utopia – you are standing in it!.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

Trackback this post  |  Subscribe to the comments via RSS Feed


Authors

Nicolai J. Foss | home | posts
Peter G. Klein | home | posts
Richard Langlois | home | posts
Lasse B. Lien | home | posts

Guests

Former Guests | posts

Networking

Recent Posts

Categories

Feeds

Our Recent Books

Nicolai J. Foss and Peter G. Klein, Organizing Entrepreneurial Judgment: A New Approach to the Firm (Cambridge University Press, 2012).
Peter G. Klein and Micheal E. Sykuta, eds., The Elgar Companion to Transaction Cost Economics (Edward Elgar, 2010).
Peter G. Klein, The Capitalist and the Entrepreneur: Essays on Organizations and Markets (Mises Institute, 2010).
Richard N. Langlois, The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism: Schumpeter, Chandler, and the New Economy (Routledge, 2007).
Nicolai J. Foss, Strategy, Economic Organization, and the Knowledge Economy: The Coordination of Firms and Resources (Oxford University Press, 2005).
Raghu Garud, Arun Kumaraswamy, and Richard N. Langlois, eds., Managing in the Modular Age: Architectures, Networks and Organizations (Blackwell, 2003).
Nicolai J. Foss and Peter G. Klein, eds., Entrepreneurship and the Firm: Austrian Perspectives on Economic Organization (Elgar, 2002).
Nicolai J. Foss and Volker Mahnke, eds., Competence, Governance, and Entrepreneurship: Advances in Economic Strategy Research (Oxford, 2000).
Nicolai J. Foss and Paul L. Robertson, eds., Resources, Technology, and Strategy: Explorations in the Resource-based Perspective (Routledge, 2000).

%d bloggers like this: